Take the cost function \(C(x) = x^3 - x^2 + x+ 1\) and the benefit function \(B(x) = 3x\text{.}\) Assume that this model measures the produce of some objects that are then sold. \(x\) can be measured in thousands of units and \(B\) and \(C\) can be measured in millions of dollars. Notice that \(C(0) = 1\text{,}\) which could represent an initial start-up cost before the production of a single unit.
I calculate the derivatives: \(C^\prime(x) = 3x^2
-2x+1\) and \(B^\prime(x) = 3\text{.}\) These are equal when \(x = \frac{1}{3} (1 \pm \sqrt{7})\text{.}\) Discarding the negative, the other root is approximately \(1.215\text{,}\) so a production of 1215 units gives the maximum net benefit. Below that point, marginal benefit exceeds cost, so I should increase production. Above that point, marginal cost will exceed benefit, so I should decrease production.
The break even points are found by solving the cubic: \(x^3
-x^2-2x+1 - 3x = 0\text{.}\) The cubic doesn’t factor nicely, but a computer can give the approximate even \(x\) values: \(-1.25\text{,}\) \(0.45\) and \(1.81\text{.}\) I discard the negative value again. The largest break-even point is at approximately \(1.81\text{.}\) All these values and the behaviour of the cost and benefit functions are shown in Figure 10.3.1.